Welcome to SPARC Forums. Please login or sign up.

Sep 07, 2024, 04:33:38 PM

Login with username, password and session length

Child Support Guidelines, Imbedded Alimony and Perverse Incentives

Special to the SPARC Web Site




The Maryland legislature has imposed child support guidelines to guide the courts in awarding child support when circumstances dictate that children cannot be raised under a single household. This includes situations where married couples separate and divorce and unmarried parents have children and do not live together.

Maryland expects both parents to be responsible for raising their children in proportion with their gross income. Thus, Maryland is one of the majority of states that use an income share model to determine child support awards. Maryland guidelines reflect the fact that, as parents combined gross incomes increase, so does the amount of funds that parents contribute towards their children. However, unlike some states, Maryland also recognizes that the amount of extra income that parents devote to children decreases as combines gross incomes grows.

However, the Maryland child support system does have shortcomings. For example, the use of combined gross incomes in calculation of child support awards is inappropriate on the grounds that the amount parents devote to raising their children is a function is disposable incomes, not gross income. Thus, the system could be improved by incorporating net income instead of gross income in defining award levels.

Additionally, Maryland’s system, as well as that of all other states, co-mingle different components of child support into one award which leads to perverse incentives.

One component of child support is real economic cost of raising children. Child support should include the cost of rearing children and Maryland has determined that each parent’s obligation should be assigned in proration to each parent’s income. For the purpose of this work, we will define this as child rearing support.

Some would argue that child rearing support is all that is necessary. However, others argue that children deserve to share in the economic status of both parents. Therefore, the child support award should consist of a standard of living component in addition to the child rearing costs.

Under this framework, there are clearly two issues at hand (1) the cost of child rearing and (2) a standard of living increment. It is clear that public policy demands the economic cost of child rearing must be paid. Thus, the cost of child rearing breaks down to a simple calculation which economists should make. If, and how much, the standard of living increment should be is a matter of public debate. Examination of the child support schedules will show that the legislature has decided that there should be a standard of living increment included in the child support award.

The purpose of this study is two-fold:

(1) to disaggregate the child support award into the cost of child rearing and standard of living increment.

(2) to show why the standard of living increment that was intended for the benefit of the children is actually imbedded nontaxable alimony and how that translates into many perverse behaviors.


General Economic Theory And Determining Real Costs.

Before gross income proration, the Maryland Child Support Guidelines define basic child support levels which are necessary to support one or more children at various levels of combined gross incomes. Depending upon the custody arrangement and the parents relative gross incomes, that amount (or 1.5 times that amount in cases of joint physical custody) will be prorated to determine each parent’s share of support. If sole custody is awarded, the custodial parent will be presumed to expend that money for the child(ren) and the noncustodial parent will pay the custodial parent his or her share. The money is deemed a reimbursement to the custodial parent and, as a result, can generally be used at the discretion of the custodial parent.

Economic costs are valued at the marginal level (2). For example, what is the cost of having a child in terms of housing? Economically, it is the increase in housing expenditures associated with the child. Therefore, if the birth of a child translates to needing a two bedroom apartment instead of a one bedroom, the marginal housing cost associated with the child would be the increase in rent between the one and two bedroom apartment. All categories of child rearing costs can be examined in the same manner. The sum of all of these marginal costs becomes the total economic cost of child rearing.

In child support development, per capita expenditures have traditionally been used. In other words, a type of average cost measure is used instead of marginal costs (3). The cost of this misapplication is inaccuracy in pricing child support awards. As the Number of Children increase the average cost per child will initially decrease. However, as the Number of Children become high, the average cost per child will increase. This will happen for capacity reasons such as the Number of Children necessitating the purchase of a larger home. Initially, the marginal cost of a child will be below the average costs. However, the marginal costs of additional children will be above average costs when average costs are increasing. Thus marginal costs will only be equal to average costs at two points: (1) when there are no children, which is an irrelevant case and (2) at the single point where average cost per child is at a minimum.

What this generally means as far as child rearing costs are concerned is that average costs will not be equal to marginal costs except by rare coincidence. Put another way, using average costs to estimate child rearing costs will be inaccurate, by design, since one is never an estimate of the other. If the average costs are above the marginal costs, too much child rearing costs are being estimated which will lead to perverse behaviors that are discussed later. If the average costs are below the marginal costs, too little child rearing costs are being estimated. In either event, child are hurt by the outcome.


Data and Methodology

In 1994, Donald Bieniewicz published an article which utilized the U.S. Department of Agriculture’s Family Economics Research Group’s (FERG) estimates of marginal costs for child rearing by category (4). Since FERG used per capita estimates for housing, Bieniewicz imputed the marginal costs of housing from a study conducted by Dr. David Garrod.

The expenditures data was based upon 1992 data and examined three cost categories of single parent families for households having 1, 2 and 3 children. Expenditures were categorized as follows [1] housing, [2] food, [3] transportation, [4] clothing, [5] health care, and [6] child care.

To make this data applicable to comparison with current Maryland Child Support Guidelines, several adjustments had to be made:

(1) Since the data was from 1992, costs had to be translated into 1999 costs. To do this, inflation was assumed to increase at the rate of 2.5 percent per year. This translated to expenditures and cost categories increasing by 19 percent.

(2) In Maryland, basic child support levels generally exclude health insurance and daycare. Hence those categories were excluded from this analysis.

(3) Transportation expenses (e.g., a car and car insurance) is generally a fixed expense and the FERG estimates were on a per capita basis. The presence of additional children generally does not increase this expense and therefore this category is excluded.

(4) Expenditure categories were only available for 1,2 and 3 children. Proper Maryland Child Support Guideline comparison would entail having this data for 4, 5 and 6 (or greater) children. Costs for 4,5 and 6 children were linearly extrapolated with a reliable statistical model (5). The model estimates were used to value the marginal expenditures for 1-6 children. This model should have overstated marginal expenditures since it was modeled as a straight linear function, instead of a decreasing linear function.

(5) Maryland child support guidelines go to $10,000 gross income per month. Because, a significant number of parents earn greater than this amount per month, the guidelines were extrapolated out to $15,000 per month using and ordinary least squares regression which fit the data virtually perfectly (6).

Estimates of Real Costs and Standard of Living Increment

Using the adjusted data, actual child rearing expenses for each cost category were calculated on a monthly basis and compared to Maryland’s child support obligation. The results are reported in Table I through VI.

The results reveal that, at low levels of gross income, child support is insufficient. For example, assume each parent earns $500 gross income per month and the mother has sole custody of one child. The guidelines would suggest that the basic child support is $198 for the child. This would be split between the parents evenly. The mother would be presumed to directly pay $99 per month and the father would be expected to pay $99 to the custodial parent to reimburse her for his share of the child’s direct expenditures. However, the true cost of raising the child is $291 (Table I). Thus the 'Standard of Living Portion' of the award is - 93 of which both parents should absorb ½. Because the mother expends the resources on the child she absorbs her half. However, she also absorbs the father’s half. Essentially, she is paying the father $46.50 in non taxable alimony per month.

The reverse occurs for higher income parents. Assume each parent in the above situation was earning $5000 per month instead of $500 per month. Under the same custody arrangement, Maryland would suggest the basic child support obligation was $1042 per month. However, the economic cost of raising that one child is $505 (Table I). Under this situation, the mother’s expenditures would be presumed and the father would pay $522 per month. Of the $522, his share of the child rearing costs would be about $202. In essence, he is paying $320 for a standard of living increment for the child.


Why Imbedded Alimony Causes Perverse Behaviors

On the face of it, the noncustodial parent is paying $320 to the mother as a benefit of his economic status to the child. In theory, these funds are to be expended to the child’s benefit. However, it is questionable how much of these funds get to the child and how much directly benefit the custodial parent. The loss of benefit to the child is certainly one problem. However, perhaps the greater problem results from the benefit to the custodial parent because the custodial parent now has an incentive to act in a manner consistent with his or own best interest at the expense of the child.

Since use of the $320 in funds is at the mother’s discretion, she will allocate the funds in a manner to achieve maximum utility (satisfaction). Standard economic theory suggests that she will expend some portion on the children and some portion on herself. Given a budget constraint ('Standard of Living Portion') and choice between two goods (goods for children versus other goods), a rational consumer will generally choose some of each good over all of one (i.e. a consumer’s indifference curve is generally convex) (7).

The ability of the custodial parent to do this is why 1/2 the 'Standard of Living Portion' that the noncustodial parent pays is, in reality, nontaxable imbedded alimony, not child support. Hence the legislatures presumed purpose of increasing the standard of living of the child does not materialize in the manner that was intended.

There are, however, other consequences to this problem. The existence of imbedded alimony generates at least two perverse incentives that are harmful to children:

(1) There is an economic incentive of the parents to now have sole custody and exclude the other parent from the child’s upbringing. Parents are now more likely to fight for sole custody at the expense of the best interests of the children. For example, it is standard practice for an attorney to warn a sole custody parent to limit contact between the child and the other parent or risk a reduction in child support award. If the child support was correctly priced, a parent would be, at worst, economicly indifferent as to whether the other parent saw the child. In fact, to the extent that the other parent taking care of the child decreases the custodial parents burden, the behavior of increased participation would be encouraged. This incentive is particularly disturbing in light of a significant body of research that show the best adjusted children of divorce are those in which both parents are involved in rearing the children.

(2) Nontaxable imbedded alimony increases the incentives to have out-of-wedlock births. Under the current child support system, having a child is an economic benefit regardless of marital status. Further, there is an incentive to have children from multiple fathers since child support schedules award the greatest percentage of child support award to gross income for one child.


Solutions to Consider:

It is generally much easier to criticize than to provide solutions. Here I will suggest some solutions designed to make the child support system work in a manner that is economicly sound and incentive neutral. The general solution I propose would be to disaggregate child support into two components, much like what has been done in this analysis. In other words, explicitly define one type of child support as child rearing support and the other type as standard of living support. Once this is achieved, these components can readily be treated differently to achieve better outcomes.

(1) Child rearing costs are the true costs of raising the child. Generally speaking, a parent should be compelled to pay this amount regardless of circumstances. This component should be expended at the sole discretion of the custodial parent since it is indeed a reimbursement for expenses incurred.

(2) 'Standard of Living Portion' should be handled differently. These funds should be mandated for the exclusive use of the children and be used at the discretion of the noncustodial parent unless a court decides that this is not in the best interest of the child. One example of this could be the noncustodial parent making direct contributions into a savings account for the children’s college education. Another example might be this component being directed into a child’s account who’s use requires the approval of the noncustodial parent. Why is the noncustodial parents discretion over this fund superior to the custodial parents discretion? Since the funds are mandated for use of the children, the noncustodial parents will maximize the children’s utility which is disassociated from his own utility (except to the degree that the noncustodial parent’s utility will be greater when the children’s utility is maximized). At a more fundamental level, this system would more closely replicate the way a child would receive the economic benefit from a parent in an intact household. Further, it would keep the noncustodial parent involved in the child’s life. In this manner, the child is ensured to receive all of the benefit of the 'Standard of Living Portion', as presumably intended by the legislature.

Finally, this would help one additional problem. Child support guidelines, across the U.S. do not take into account children and families subsequent to divorce. All children have a right for equal support from their parents, however, the court has a difficult time equating children from different marriages (or unmarried arrangements) since each parent-child set in handled separately. The clearly defined distinction between child rearing costs and standard of living increment radically simplifies a court’s analysis of the problem. For example, the court may decide that the cost of child rearing is inflexible and the 'Standard of Living Portion' should be split between the all children.


Concluding Remarks

The purpose of this analysis is to simplify the child support problem, reduce perverse incentives which leads competing parents to act in a manner inconsistent with the best interests of the children. As this paper suggests, separating awards into components and handling them different can go a long way toward improving the system.

Estimating real costs of child rearing is a relatively simple application of an economist’s trade. This can be done in an objective manner, devoid of political jockeying. The standard of living increment is a matter of pubic debate. However, whether the legislature decides that the appropriate amount of funds should be zero or half of the noncustodial parent’s pay is irrelevant as long as this portion of funds is clearly defined, separable from the cost of child rearing and is expended at the discretion of the noncustodial parent.
Companion Document: Why Imbedded Alimony in Child Support Causes Perverse Behaviors





Notes



[1] Hans Dutt is an economist with the Office of the Actuary of the Health Care Financing Administration. Mr. Dutt has conducted this research
in his private capacity as a citizen and the work was conducted outside the scope of Mr. Dutt’s employment. The opinions expressed within
are Mr. Dutt’s alone and do not necessarily reflect that of the Health Care Financing Administration, the Department of Health and Human
Services or any other part of the U.S. Government. Send any comments to: Hans Dutt, Data Analysis Group of Columbia, 7578 Rainflower
Way, Columbia, MD 21046.




[2] Elementary economics tells us that total cost of child rearing is a function of the Number of Children. The change in the total cost with respect
to the change in the Number of Children yields the marginal cost of child rearing. Marginal cost of child rearing, or the cost of having an additional
child, will initially decrease at low Number of Children and, at some point, start to increase. The concept of estimating marginal costs is one of the
most fundamental concepts in economics. See: Price Theory and Application, 4th edition (Prentice-Hall (1988)) by Jack Hirshleifer for a basic introduction.




[3] Strictly speaking, the framework of the discussion is the relation between average costs per child and marginal costs per child. Per capita costs
add in one/two parents in the denominator when calculating the average. This essentially means that average costs are lowered to some degree. However,
the central theme holds: Marginal costs reflect real costs and average costs will generally be greater or less than these real costs and cannot approximate
the real costs of child rearing.




[4] The article, "Child Support Guideline Developed by the Children’s Rights Council" appeared in Child Support Guidelines: The Next Generation
(U.S. Health and Human Services, Administration for Children and Families, Office of Child Support Enforcement (1994)).




[5] Each cost category was estimated as a function of the Number of Children through an ordinary least squares regression. In general the R-squared was
in the 90 percent region and the parameters were significantly different from zero.




[6] Working paper by Hans R. Dutt, "An Optimal Statistical Model for Extrapolating Maryland Child Support Guidelines", March, 1999




[7] For a more in-depth discussion on utility, preference and rational choice see Price Theory and Applications by Hirshleifer.








Table I - Calculation of Imbedded Nontaxable Alimony

Child Support Awards versus Economic Costs of Child Rearing

Maryland Child Support Guidelines

Number of Children

Gross Monthly Income

Basic Support Obligation

Economic Cost of Child-Rearing

Standard of Living Portion

1 1000 198.00 291.385 -93.388
1 1500 266.80 291.385 -24.584
1 2000 333.96 291.385 42.572
1 2500 383.09 291.385 91.709
1 3000 438.46 291.385 147.072
1 3500 498.50 402.947 95.556
1 4000 559.23 402.947 156.285
1 4500 618.01 402.947 215.059
1 5000 673.48 402.947 270.536
1 5500 725.13 504.593 220.537
1 6000 772.86 504.593 268.270
1 6500 816.82 504.593 312.231
1 7000 857.26 504.593 352.670
1 7500 894.47 504.593 389.876
1 8000 928.74 504.593 424.142
1 8500 960.34 504.593 455.750
1 9000 989.55 504.593 484.959
1 9500 1016.60 504.593 512.005
1 10000 1041.69 504.593 537.100
1 10500 1065.02 504.593 560.431
1 11000 1086.76 504.593 582.169
1 11500 1107.05 504.593 602.462
1 12000 1126.04 504.593 621.442
1 12500 1143.82 504.593 639.229
1 13000 1160.52 504.593 655.928
1 13500 1176.22 504.593 671.631
1 14000 1191.02 504.593 686.423
1 14500 1204.97 504.593 700.380
1 15000 1218.16 504.593 713.567











Table II - Calculation of Imbedded Nontaxable Alimony

Child Support Awards versus Economic Costs of Child Rearing

Maryland Child Support Guidelines

Number of Children

Gross Monthly Income

Basic Support Obligation

Economic Cost of Child-Rearing

Standard of Living Portion

2 1000 307.01 403.939 -96.926
2 1500 412.55 403.939 8.611
2 2000 517.66 403.939 113.719
2 2500 594.77 403.939 190.832
2 3000 681.26 403.939 277.323
2 3500 774.80 563.597 211.201
2 4000 869.25 563.597 305.649
2 4500 960.57 563.597 396.970
2 5000 1046.71 563.597 483.114
2 5500 1126.88 711.356 415.520
2 6000 1200.94 711.356 489.584
2 6500 1269.14 711.356 557.780
2 7000 1331.86 711.356 620.501
2 7500 1389.55 711.356 678.20
2 8000 1442.69 711.356 731.33
2 8500 1491.69 711.356 780.34
2 9000 1536.98 711.356 825.62
2 9500 1578.90 711.356 867.55
2 10000 1617.80 711.356 906.45
2 10500 1653.97 711.356 942.61
2 11000 1687.66 711.356 976.30
2 11500 1719.11 711.356 1007.75
2 12000 1748.52 711.356 1037.17
2 12500 1776.09 711.356 1064.73
2 13000 1801.97 711.356 1090.61
2 13500 1826.30 711.356 1114.95
2 14000 1849.22 711.356 1137.87
2 14500 1870.85 711.356 1159.49
2 15000 1891.28 711.356 1179.93












Table III - Calculation of Imbedded Nontaxable Alimony

Child Support Awards versus Economic Costs of Child Rearing

Maryland Child Support Guidelines

Number of Children

Gross Monthly Income

Basic Support Obligation

Economic Cost of Child-Rearing

Standard of Living Portion

3 1000 332.07 516.493 -184.42
3 1500 515.61 516.493 -0.89
3 2000 650.56 516.493 134.06
3 2500 745.68 516.493 229.18
3 3000 852.62 516.493 336.13
3 3500 968.93 724.247 244.69
3 4000 1086.83 724.247 362.58
3 4500 1201.09 724.247 476.84
3 5000 1309.05 724.247 584.80
3 5500 1409.63 918.118 491.51
3 6000 1502.63 918.118 584.51
3 6500 1588.32 918.118 670.20
3 7000 1667.17 918.118 749.05
3 7500 1739.73 918.118 821.61
3 8000 1806.58 918.118 888.46
3 8500 1868.25 918.118 950.13
3 9000 1925.24 918.118 1007.12
3 9500 1978.02 918.118 1059.91
3 10000 2027.00 918.118 1108.88
3 10500 2072.54 918.118 1154.43
3 11000 2114.98 918.118 1196.86
3 11500 2154.59 918.118 1236.48
3 12000 2191.65 918.118 1273.53
3 12500 2226.38 918.118 1308.26
3 13000 2258.99 918.118 1340.87
3 13500 2289.65 918.118 1371.53
3 14000 2318.54 918.118 1400.42
3 14500 2345.79 918.118 1427.67
3 15000 2371.54 918.118 1453.43













Table IV - Calculation of Imbedded Nontaxable Alimony

Child Support Awards versus Economic Costs of Child Rearing

Maryland Child Support Guidelines

Number of Children

Gross Monthly Income

Basic Support Obligation

Economic Cost of Child-Rearing

Standard of Living Portion

4 1000 336.03 629.05 -293.01
4 1500 583.09 629.05 -45.96
4 2000 731.94 629.05 102.90
4 2500 839.24 629.05 210.19
4 3000 960.74 629.05 331.69
4 3500 1092.60 884.90 207.70
4 4000 1225.85 884.90 340.95
4 4500 1354.67 884.90 469.78
4 5000 1476.15 884.90 591.25
4 5500 1589.15 1124.88 464.27
4 6000 1693.50 1124.88 568.62
4 6500 1789.55 1124.88 664.67
4 7000 1877.86 1124.88 752.98
4 7500 1959.07 1124.88 834.19
4 8000 2033.83 1124.88 908.95
4 8500 2102.77 1124.88 977.89
4 9000 2166.45 1124.88 1041.57
4 9500 2225.41 1124.88 1100.53
4 10000 2280.09 1124.88 1155.21
4 10500 2330.93 1124.88 1206.05
4 11000 2378.28 1124.88 1253.40
4 11500 2422.47 1124.88 1297.59
4 12000 2463.80 1124.88 1338.92
4 12500 2502.53 1124.88 1377.65
4 13000 2538.88 1124.88 1414.00
4 13500 2573.06 1124.88 1448.18
4 14000 2605.25 1124.88 1480.37
4 14500 2635.62 1124.88 1510.74
4 15000 2664.31 1124.88 1539.43











Table V - Calculation of Imbedded Nontaxable Alimony

Child Support Awards versus Economic Costs of Child Rearing

Maryland Child Support Guidelines

Number of Children

Gross Monthly Income

Basic Support Obligation

Economic Cost of Child-Rearing

Standard of Living Portion

5 1000 340.00 741.60 -401.60
5 1500 622.56 741.60 -119.04
5 2000 796.68 741.60 55.08
5 2500 916.41 741.60 174.81
5 3000 1049.11 741.60 307.51
5 3500 1192.61 1045.55 147.06
5 4000 1337.66 1045.55 292.11
5 4500 1478.03 1045.55 432.48
5 5000 1610.53 1045.55 564.98
5 5500 1733.89 1331.64 402.25
5 6000 1847.91 1331.64 516.26
5 6500 1952.92 1331.64 621.27
5 7000 2049.52 1331.64 717.87
5 7500 2138.39 1331.64 806.75
5 8000 2220.25 1331.64 888.61
5 8500 2295.76 1331.64 964.12
5 9000 2365.54 1331.64 1033.89
5 9500 2430.15 1331.64 1098.50
5 10000 2490.09 1331.64 1158.45
5 10500 2545.83 1331.64 1214.19
5 11000 2597.76 1331.64 1266.12
5 11500 2646.24 1331.64 1314.59
5 12000 2691.58 1331.64 1359.94
5 12500 2734.07 1331.64 1402.43
5 13000 2773.96 1331.64 1442.32
5 13500 2811.47 1331.64 1479.83
5 14000 2846.81 1331.64 1515.17
5 14500 2880.15 1331.64 1548.51
5 15000 2911.65 1331.64 1580.01












Table VI - Calculation of Imbedded Nontaxable Alimony

Child Support Awards versus Economic Costs of Child Rearing

Maryland Child Support Guidelines

Number of Children

Gross Monthly Income

Basic Support Obligation

Economic Cost of Child-Rearing

Standard of Living Portion

6 1000 342.91 854.16 -511.241
6 1500 629.98 854.16 -224.172
6 2000 847.28 854.16 -6.874
6 2500 983.00 854.16 128.845
6 3000 1125.07 854.16 270.915
6 3500 1277.00 1206.20 70.807
6 4000 1430.61 1206.20 224.415
6 4500 1579.64 1206.20 373.439
6 5000 1720.69 1206.20 514.494
6 5500 1852.34 1538.41 313.935
6 6000 1974.28 1538.41 435.870
6 6500 2086.78 1538.41 548.379
6 7000 2190.44 1538.41 652.039
6 7500 2285.95 1538.41 747.54
6 8000 2374.01 1538.41 835.60
6 8500 2455.32 1538.41 916.91
6 9000 2530.53 1538.41 992.12
6 9500 2600.22 1538.41 1061.82
6 10000 2664.93 1538.41 1126.53
6 10500 2725.14 1538.41 1186.73
6 11000 2781.26 1538.41 1242.86
6 11500 2833.68 1538.41 1295.27
6 12000 2882.73 1538.41 1344.33
6 12500 2928.72 1538.41 1390.32
6 13000 2971.91 1538.41 1433.51
6 13500 3012.54 1538.41 1474.14
6 14000 3050.83 1538.41 1512.42
6 14500 3086.96 1538.41 1548.56
6 15000 3121.12 1538.41 1582.71



Articles in « Studies and Statistical Information »